Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.
- View all journals
- My Account Login
- Explore content
- About the journal
- Publish with us
- Sign up for alerts
- Open access
- Published: 17 October 2023
The momentum of the solar energy transition
- Femke J. M. M. Nijsse ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-6674-5350 1 ,
- Jean-Francois Mercure ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0003-2620-9200 1 , 2 , 3 ,
- Nadia Ameli ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-6728-9190 4 ,
- Francesca Larosa ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-4350-8790 4 , 5 ,
- Sumit Kothari ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-4560-1059 4 ,
- Jamie Rickman 4 ,
- Pim Vercoulen ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-2468-5513 1 , 6 &
- Hector Pollitt 2 , 3
Nature Communications volume 14 , Article number: 6542 ( 2023 ) Cite this article
105k Accesses
68 Citations
2310 Altmetric
Metrics details
- Energy modelling
- Solar energy
Decarbonisation plans across the globe require zero-carbon energy sources to be widely deployed by 2050 or 2060. Solar energy is the most widely available energy resource on Earth, and its economic attractiveness is improving fast in a cycle of increasing investments. Here we use data-driven conditional technology and economic forecasting modelling to establish which zero carbon power sources could become dominant worldwide. We find that, due to technological trajectories set in motion by past policy, a global irreversible solar tipping point may have passed where solar energy gradually comes to dominate global electricity markets, without any further climate policies. Uncertainties arise, however, over grid stability in a renewables-dominated power system, the availability of sufficient finance in underdeveloped economies, the capacity of supply chains and political resistance from regions that lose employment. Policies resolving these barriers may be more effective than price instruments to accelerate the transition to clean energy.
Similar content being viewed by others
Plausible energy demand patterns in a growing global economy with climate policy
Early decarbonisation of the European energy system pays off
An assessment of energy system transformation pathways to achieve net-zero carbon dioxide emissions in Switzerland
Introduction.
A rapid transformation of the energy system is necessary to keep warming well below 2 °C, as set out in the Paris Agreement and reinforced in the Glasgow Pact. Many countries have committed to achieving net-zero targets by 2050 (incl. EU, UK, Japan, Korea), 2060 (China) or 2070 (India). Net-zero targets imply mass-scale deployment of zero-carbon energy technologies such as solar and wind power, likely in combination with negative emission technologies 1 . However, the potential for negative emissions to compensate positive emissions remains relatively limited 2 , 3 .
Renewables have historically been considered expensive, their deployment requiring high subsidies or carbon taxes 4 , 5 . However, following a fruitful history of innovation and past climate policy, renewables now increasingly compete with fossil fuels 6 , 7 . Whether renewables become the new normal increasingly hinges upon industry and trade development rather than a pure normative necessity to meet carbon budgets 7 , 8 , 9 . Policy-makers urgently need to know not only whether a renewables future is possible, but whether it is materialising.
Between 2010 and 2020, the cost of solar PV fell by 15% each year, representing a technological learning rate of around 20% per doubling of installed capacity 8 . At the same time, the installed capacity has risen by 25% per year, causing and partly caused by these cost reductions. Meanwhile, onshore wind capacity grew by 12% a year, with a learning rate of 10% per doubling of capacity 8 , 9 . If these rates of rapid co-evolution are maintained, solar PV and wind power appear ready to irreversibly become the dominant electricity technologies within 1-2 decades, as their costs and rate of growth far undercut all alternatives. Were that to be the case, a renewables tipping point in the power sector could be imminent or even already have been passed, and the policy and finance spheres should prepare for a rapid disruptive transition. Despite this evidence, the energy modelling community has not yet identified this possibility with any degree of consensus 8 , suggesting instead that fossil fuel-dominated electricity systems would likely continue as a result from inadequate carbon pricing.
The problem of high cost for renewables has changed into a problem of balancing electricity grids, in which large amounts of intermittent wind and solar generation pose challenges. Batteries play an important role in mitigating that issue and show a similarly high learning rate 10 . This implies that electricity storage costs and diffusion could follow a comparable and coupled trajectory to PV in the 2020s.
Whether solar and wind can dominate electricity grids depends on the ability of the technology to overcome a series of barriers. This includes how to deal with the seasonal variation for which batteries are ill-suited 11 . The cost of managing large amounts of intermittency could offset further cost reductions in solar panels and wind turbines, impeding their rapid diffusion 12 . The unequal availability of finance to support solar and wind investments in various countries 13 may be an issue, too. Supply chains may be poorly prepared for such a rapid technological roll out 14 . Finally, political resistance in areas of declining fossil fuel use or trade could curb the willingness of governments to embrace a solar revolution 15 .
Here, we use a global, data-driven energy-technology-economy simulation model (E3ME-FTT) to conditionally forecast the deployment of energy technologies up to 2060, under current policy regimes. We focus on identifying the existence of a tipping point for solar and wind, assuming that no further policy is adopted to usher in a solar and wind-dominated electricity system. We then explore in detail the various barriers that could impede this renewables revolution, and identify what non-traditional policies could be used to bridge those gaps.
Historical projections of energy generation have consistently underestimated uptake rates of solar energy 16 , 17 . For example, only a year after the publication of the 2020 World Energy Outlook (WEO), the IEA’s “Stated policies scenario” has been revised strongly in favour of solar energy. Nevertheless, the total share of solar in power production only reaches 20% by 2050 in that baseline scenario despite historically low prices 18 . Systematic underestimation of low-carbon technology deployment in energy models could stem from systematic lack of suitable or realistic representation of induced innovation and diffusion processes 19 , 20 , 21 .
Solar energy started its journey in niche markets, like most innovations, supplying electricity to applications where little alternatives existed in space and remote locations 22 . Since then, cumulative investments and sales, driven by past policy, have made its cost come down by almost three orders of magnitude. The introduction of feed-in tariffs in mainly Germany induced a volume of investment and related cost reductions, that brought the technology to mainstream markets following Chinese involvement in supply chains 7 .
Cost reductions and rapid deployment work hand in hand, something observed for many technologies 7 . Deployments typically follow Rogers’ S-curve diffusion 23 , with a bi-directional interaction with cost reductions from Wright’s law 24 . For solar (and wind), rapid deployments, supported by past policies, have pushed down technology costs. This promotes further diffusion in a virtuous cycle 7 . Such nonlinearity in the diffusion process raises the possibility of an irreversible tipping point 25 .
There are many reasons why solar has experienced such high learning rates. Its simplicity, modularity and mass-scale replicability allow for significant learning opportunities, related to those seen across the electronics industry 26 , 27 , 28 . Indeed, numerous spillovers have originated from the computer industry 22 . Innovation and improvements to solar PV are ongoing. For instance, the commercialisation of (hybrid) perovskite cells holds promises for higher efficiencies and lower unit prices 29 , 30 . Due to decreasing technology risks and financial learning, finance is partly cheaper to procure 31 . Progress in recycling helps material supply security and may decrease life-cycle costs 32 . Meanwhile, the chemical diversity of batteries, a storage technology highly supportive of solar PV, makes it likely that further cost declines can be achieved 33 .
The historical failure of the modelling community to anticipate the rapid progress of solar power could stem from an over-reliance outdated data, the lack of use of learning curves, and the imposition of maximum deployment levels and floor costs 16 , 34 . As the primary innovation in this paper, forecasting technology evolution and induced innovation can more effectively be achieved based on evolutionary simulations, using the most recent data available, that focus on the two-way positive feedback between induced innovation and diffusion 24 , 35 .
This work supplements recent research by Way et al. 16 . Way et al. developed a probabilistic empirically validated global model of energy technology costs. The research showed that a scenario of high renewables uptake leads to a significantly lower-cost energy system, and the authors argued that energy models should be updated to reflect the high probability of low-cost renewables. This paper differs in two key ways: 1) we do not impose a scenario, but rather allow investor decisions to dictate the deployment of technologies. 2) we use a globally disaggregated model and look at region-specific alternative sources of electricity.
Towards a new baseline scenario
Following the recent progress of renewables, fossil fuel-dominated projection baselines are not realistic anymore. Here, we focus on the co-evolving dynamics of diffusion and innovation to project the mid to long-term diffusion trajectory of 24 power technologies. We use the historical data-driven E3ME-FTT integrated energy-economy model, in which a system dynamics simulation method, combined with choice modelling (see Methods), tracks the positive feedbacks that emerge between cost reductions and diffusion, something not usually represented in models that have fixed yearly learning 5 . We use IEA data for historical generation, CAPEX and OPEX, BNEF for capacity factors, construction and lifetimes until 2020, IRENA for historical renewables capacity data between 2019 and 2021.
Technological trajectories typically have inertia in their diffusion that depend on their lifecycle turnover, with half-lives ranging between 10 and 15 years for short-lived units (cars), 25–40 years for fossil fuel plants, and 50–100 years for long-lived infrastructure, such as nuclear plants and hydro dams 36 . These long lifetimes prevent technological trajectories from changing direction abruptly. This autocorrelation time in the direction of evolution (or degree of inertia) implies that energy system technological forecasting constrained by observed diffusion and cost trajectories, as done here, can be reliable within at least 15-20 years, subject to an increasing error that cumulates over the simulation time span.
Figure 1 shows the global share of electricity production of 11 key technologies (Supplementary Figure 1 for a regional breakdown). The current mix is highly varied. By mid-century, according to E3ME-FTT, solar PV will have come to dominate the mix, even without any additional policies supporting renewables. This is due to solar costs declining far below the costs of all alternatives, while its parent industrial supply capacity increases rapidly. Its scale expands, because of its current rapid and exponential diffusion trajectory and comparatively high learning rate. Even the market shares of onshore and offshore wind power in the global electricity mix start declining around 2030, outpaced by solar. This is due to a lower learning rate of wind compared to solar and a growing cost gap in the model. However, onshore continues growing in absolute terms until 2040, and offshore to the end of the simulation. Concentrated solar power grows over the entire period, but without targeted policy its overall share in the power mix remains small, despite its advantage as a dispatchable source of electricity.
In 2020, fossil fuels produce 62% of electricity. This percentage reduces to 21% in 2050, with solar responsible for 56% of production.
The trend towards renewables dominance (Fig. 2a ) and notably solar PV (Fig. 2b ) appears imminent in China, and lags in Africa and Russia. Africa lags despite a very high technical potential and low seasonality. The slow uptake can mostly be attributed to nonpecuniary aspects (grid flexibility, trust in new technologies), which requires prices to fall further below alternatives before there is significant uptake. This occurs after uptake by other countries drives down prices further.
a total renewables (hydro + wind + solar + biomass) and ( b ) solar PV. Initially, renewables are dominated by hydropower and to a lesser extent wind. This is soon overtaken by solar, depending on regional factors.
The levelised cost of electricity (LCOE ssc , which includes system storage costs, see Methods) is shown in Fig. 3 . We tentatively assign additional system costs for storage to be borne by renewable energy producers. Even though storage needs increase substantially over time, LCOE for solar energy decreases overall. This is because the learning rate for short-term storage is very high, and the learning rate for long-duration storage (we assume hydrogen is used for seasonal storage) is expected to be relatively high too 8 . Of the major countries shown, solar PV is initially more expensive than coal only in Japan, where cost-parity is reached around 2025.
a EU-27 ( b ) United States ( c ) India ( d ) China ( e ) Japan and ( f ) Brazil. Shaded areas are the 10–90% confidence interval. Solar PV + system storage is already among the cheapest forms of electricity. In some regions, wind and solar remain competitive, whereas solar becomes much cheaper in others. Without carbon taxation, coal is typically cheaper than gas.
In 2020, wind energy has the lowest LCOE in a majority the 70 regions defined in the E3ME-FTT models (Fig. 4 ). Where this is not the case, solar PV, nuclear or coal dominate. By 2030, this has flipped, in favour in solar power across most of the world (see Supplementary Figs. 2 and 3 for worst/best case maps). We assume a uniform declining cost per kW of PV panels worldwide, with differing solar irradiation for each region. This assumption is based on empirical findings 37 . Due to this international spillover effect, most regions of the world are likely going to gain access to low-cost solar energy. As such, a region may reach cost parity between solar and the cheapest alternative through the influence of other countries on the scale of production and costs, even if cumulative investments in that region are modest. This implies that developing countries could become realistic markets for solar energy even when the capacity of their governments to implement climate policies remains limited.
Each map shows the 70 E3ME regions: in 2020 ( a ), 2023 ( b ), 2027 ( c ) and 2030 ( d ). The biggest shift occurs between 2020 and 2027, which sees a range of technologies give way to solar PV as the cheapest source of electricity.
Figure 5 shows the robustness of the result to a set of model assumptions (see Methods). The two most important sources of uncertainty are potential delays in making necessary grid adjustments and the learning rate for wind power. If installing solar power plants takes twice as long due to delays with grid expansions, the median share of solar in 2050 drops by 16 percentage points. Notably, with solar prices far below alternatives, higher learning rates have a small effect on diffusion. Overall, in 72% of the simulations done for robustness testing, solar makes up more than 50% of power generation in 2050. This suggests that solar dominance is not only possible but also likely.
a The overall histogram of the 2050 shares of solar PV. b The shares solar PV depending on who pays for storage costs (variable renewable energy (VRE) sources, or the grid operator). Box plot elements: Centre line: median, box limit: upper and lower quartiles, whiskers: 1.5x interquartile range, points: outliers c , Shares of solar PV depending on the learning rate of onshore and offshore wind energy, d , depending on the learning rate of solar PV and e , depending on the lead time for solar projects.
These projections and sensitivities give us some confidence to suggest that realistic energy model baselines should, from now on, include substantially larger shares of solar energy than what is commonly assumed, as they make coal and gas-dominated baseline scenarios largely unrealistic. The main scenario framework assessed in the IPCC reports, the socialeconomic pathways (SSPs), include scenarios with increasing reliance on coal to the energy mix 38 . This work notably indicates these scenarios are highly improbable.
The above projections appear robust with respect to cost and technical factors included in the model. However, systemic problems not modelled could, nevertheless, develop into barriers hindering achieving climate targets. This suggests that further climate policy action should focus on addressing these barriers.
Overcoming barriers
We highlight four barriers that go beyond considerations of levelized costs and a) may significantly slow down the solar tipping point if unaddressed b) are global and c) are not fully implemented into integrated assessment models. The four identified encompass the technological, policy, market and economic, regulatory, political and social barriers identified by the literature 39 as the most relevant for solar PV deployment in the next three decades.
As a first barrier, we consider grid resilience. In many published energy scenarios with higher shares of solar and wind power, “dark doldrums”, periods of simultaneously low wind speeds and solar irradiation, form the predominant vulnerability 40 . From geophysical constraints, it is possible to compute an optimal mix of wind and solar power, which maximises the match between supply and demand. The typical optimal share of solar when 12 h of battery storage is available lies between 10–70%, depending on geography. Where less storage is available, the optimal mix shifts towards more wind power 11 . When either of the two main technologies is (near)-absent, the grid becomes more vulnerable to weather fluctuations. As such, solar-dominated grids may not be desirable. Importantly, no mechanism guarantees that optimal grids are achieved if left to market forces, especially in contexts of diverging technology costs, and solar dominance could become self-limiting. While E3ME-FTT models grid constraints of a typical year, weather extremes are not considered.
The self-limiting effect of solar PV diffusion due to intermittency can be overcome with a policy mix supporting wind power and other zero-carbon energy sources, as well as improved storage, grid connections and demand-response. Notably, new power market rules can be designed to incentivise investment in generators that complement solar production on a daily to seasonal scale, according to the savings in storage that they generate. Specifically, our model suggests that the allocation of storage costs to the grid and charged directly to consumers incentivises more renewables diffusion than requiring renewables to carry the full burden of storage needs (see Fig. 5 ), leading to lower overall system costs 41 .
Secondly, the availability of finance may act as a barrier. Solar growth trajectories will inevitably depend on the availability of finance. Low-carbon finance is presently highly concentrated in high-income countries 42 . Even international North-South flows largely favour middle-income countries, leaving lower income countries – particularly those in Africa – deficient in solar finance despite the enormous investment potential 42 .
This unequal distribution of finance reflects different investment risk considerations across countries. Differences in local financial environments, such as macroeconomic conditions, business confidence, policy uncertainty and regulatory frameworks impact risk perceptions and the willingness to invest by domestic and international actors 13 . Equity investors and financial lenders apply high-risk premiums in perceived risky regional contexts, thus increasing the cost of capital for renewable projects 13 , 43 .
Developing countries are particularly financially and fiscally constrained. Domestically they are characterised by under-developed capital markets and lack capital stock 44 ; whereas international finance is restricted due to high sovereign risks and local currency risks on account of volatile economic fundamentals (as projects are funded with foreign currency while returns are generated in local currencies 45 , 46 ). This leads to a chronic lack of available finance to support investments in solar energy.
Energy sector deficiencies further exacerbate the negative investment outlook for solar projects. Weak contract enforcement, changing energy regulations, and underdeveloped electricity markets affect project returns and investment viability. Developing countries may also face high import costs due to shortages in foreign currency reserves needed to support an expanding solar sector.
Consequently, a key challenge for global solar deployment lies in the mismatch between high investment needs (see Fig. 6 for modelled investment needs) and finance flows mobilised in developing countries 44 . Latest estimates suggest that climate financial flows would need to increase by a factor 4 to 8 in most vulnerable countries (IPCC 2022) 47 . Strategies to address this finance gap should include mechanisms to absorb currency and investment risk as a bridge to unlock international capital flows while creating domestic financial capacity over time.
a shows power sector investments as a percentage of GDP. The strong peak around 2030 for China and India is explained by a saturation in addition of additional solar capacity, in combination with a growing GDP and declining solar costs. b shows power sector investment with respect to 2019 values. Investment is forecast to see a fast growth worldwide relative to historical trends. Various regions in the Global South, in particular India and Africa, will see an even steeper rise in investment in generating capacity by mid-century, due to projected rapid economic growth.
As a third barrier, we discuss supply chains. A solar-dominated future is likely to be metal and mineral-intensive 48 . Future demand for “critical minerals” will increase on two fronts: electrification and batteries require large-scale raw materials – such as lithium and copper; niche materials, including tellurium, are instrumental for solar panels 49 . As countries accelerate their decarbonisation efforts, renewable technologies are projected to make up 40% of total mineral demand for copper and rare earth elements, between 60 and 70% for nickel and cobalt, and almost 90% for lithium by 2040 14 .
The notion of criticality comes in three forms: physical, economic, and geopolitical. Firstly, there are risk associated with low reserves. Secondly, minerals supply typically reacts slowly to short-term changes in demand in, due to the long times required to establish mineral supply chains. This could lead to price rallies. The construction of new mining facilities (from exploration to mine operations) requires on average 16.5 years 14 and may be stalled due to concerns about socio-environmental impacts 50 .
The geopolitical supply reliability of critical minerals is also weak, since mineral production displays higher geographical concentration, compared to fossil fuels production. China and The Democratic Republic of Congo, for example, own 60% and 70% of current global production of rare earth minerals and cobalt respectively 51 . Domestic shocks, including growing climate risks and political instability, could hamper the extraction and production and generate price shocks that along the value chain, impacting solar technology costs. Electricity networks could suffer similar impacts for nickel and aluminium.
Risk associated with low reserves can be mitigated with (research into) substitutions 52 . Recycling and circular economy processes can further reduce extraction rates, but re-used materials are unlikely to meet future demand as it outgrows existing stocks 53 .
Lastly, resistance from declining industries may impact the transition. The pace of the transition depends not only on (economic) decisions by entrepreneurs, but also on how desirable policy makers consider it. Solar energy aligns with many policy objectives (clean air, poverty alleviation, energy security 54 ). It also has disadvantages for some of the players involved, as it leads to rapid economic and industrial change.
Solar and wind power have a low energy density compared to alternatives. In most countries, they can provide enough energy to meet demand. However, land for renewables may be scarce close to population centres in some parts of the world 55 , 56 . Political tension on the use of land and water (for floating photovoltaics 57 ) may increase as solar shares rise.
A rapid solar transition may also put at risk the livelihood of up to 13 million people worldwide working in fossil fuel industries and dependent industries. These people are frequently concentrated in communities close to mines extraction and industrial sites, where the closure of these activities can have severe repercussion on the well-being of communities decades on 58 . Policy makers could have substantial incentives to slow down the transition to limit these direct impacts. Similarly, many countries currently provide fossil fuel subsidies to increase the purchasing power of low-income households, difficult to phase out and which reinforce opposition to change. New coalitions of actors who benefit from the transition (home and landowners, people with jobs in clean energy), may counterbalance some of the resistance from incumbents 15 , but do not resolve equity issues. Regional economic and industrial development policy can resolve inequity, and can mitigate risks posed by resistance from declining industries 59 .
Without any further energy policy changes, solar energy appears to follow a robust trajectory to become the future dominant power source before mid-century. Due to the reinforcing co-evolution of technology costs and deployment, our analysis establishes quantitative empirical evidence, from current and historical data trends, that a solar energy tipping point is likely to have passed. Once the combined cost of solar and storage crosses cost parity with all alternative technologies in several key markets, its widespread deployment and further costs declines globally could become irreversible. This echoes the results from Way et al. 16 , who showed that such a configuration would be cheaper than alternatives 60 .
A tipping point towards solar dominance however does not solve climate change mitigation or achieve climate targets, as it does not ensure a zero-carbon energy system. Solar-dominated electricity systems could become locked into configurations that are neither resilient nor sustainable with a reliance on fossil fuel for dispatchable power. Issues that could hinder achieving zero-carbon energy systems include grid stability issues, the availability of financial capital and critical minerals, and the willingness of decision-makers to get onboard a rapid transition that could generate substantial distributional issues in their respective regions. The energy crisis resulting from the war in Ukraine suggests that the accelerated move away from fossil fuels is needed even more urgently.
We conclude that achieving zero-carbon power systems likely requires policies of a different kind than have traditionally been discussed by the energy modelling community. The carbon price required to achieve cost break-even between renewables and fossil fuels may soon be zero. Instead, it is policies that address the above barriers—grid resilience, access to finance, management of material supply chains and political opposition—that may enable success in reaching net-zero energy emissions.
E3ME-FTT-GENIE 61 is a model based on path-dependent simulation parameterised by historical data and technology diffusion trajectories. Integrated assessment models are typically based on utility or whole-system cost optimisation. Those models have played an important role in the energy debate by characterising what an optimal composition of the energy system ought to look like. They are less suitable for studying trends in energy system dynamics since, being driven by a centralised social planner construct, they neglect historical relationships, economic causality structures and decision-making processes 35 , 62 . In contrast, path-dependent energy system and economy simulations model system evolution on the basis of known causality structures and decision-making parameterised by timeseries and other data, however they do not identify optimal system configurations or policy. Decision-making by investors does not always line up with an optimal system, as investors use shorter time-scales to evaluate decisions compared to a putative ‘social planner’.
In this paper, we use the energy-economy-environment (E3) simulation model E3ME-FTT-GENIE. It is grounded in empirically derived relationships between economic and technology variables, under the highest sectoral and regional disaggregation available for a global model (43 sectors and 70 regions) and a large number of energy technologies (88 technologies). Evolutionary dynamics form the core of technology evolution where induced innovation plays an important role; those sectors are represented by the various FTT submodels, which portray the typical S-shaped dynamics of technology uptake 63 . The model includes energy markets for nonrenewable and renewable energy. The GENIE climate and carbon cycle model is soft-coupled – emissions from E3ME-FTT drive the GENIE, but the GENIE does not affect the global economy. A complete set of equations for the E3ME-FTT model is given in Mercure et al. 61 , with updates for the Power model found in Simsek et al. 41 .
The Future Technology Transformation (FTT) family of models provide an in-depth representation of four climate-relevant sectors in which technological change plays an important role: power, transport 64 , heating 65 and steel 66 . These are the four energy end-use sectors with the highest greenhouse gas emissions. The models are based on evolutionary dynamics, simulating the S-curve of technology uptake characteristic of innovation 23 . Its core is the replicator dynamics equation (known as the Lotka-Volterra equation), prominent in ecosystem population dynamics modelling 67 .
The direction of diffusion of a technology in FTT is primarily driven by comparing the levelised cost of technology options in chains of binary discrete choice models, where the frequency of choice options availability is weighted by the share of those options in the technology mix. The levelised costs being compared are designed as to be a suitable depiction of decision making in each specific sector. A factor is included in each levelised cost, that captures non-pecuniary aspects otherwise not be captured with available data on costs alone. These are calibrated to match observed diffusion trajectories for each technology. For instance, technologies that are more socially attractive than their market costs suggest will have a negative factor included in the LCOE.
Power represents the diffusion of 24 technologies in the power sector. It includes nuclear, a set of bio-energy technologies, seven technologies based on the combustion of fossil fuels (including CCS options). Onshore and offshore wind, solar PV and CSP, hydro power, tidal, geothermal and wave power are also represented. FTT:Heat depicts the competition between various combustion technologies (oil, coal, wood and gas- burning) in households, as well as electrified heating options (resistive electric heating and heat pump technologies) and finally district and solar heating. FTT:Transport models the competition between petrol, diesel, LPG, EVs and hybrid passenger vehicles, as well as motor vehicles. For each base technology, there is a further disaggregation based on the luxury of the vehicle. Finally, FTT:Steel models 25 different routes of steel production: on the basis of coal, gas, hydrogen and electricity.
FTT Power follows Ueckerdt et al. 68 in its detailed representation of variable renewables in grid stability. Technologies are classified along six load bands, and production is allocated to available technologies based on intermittency and flexibility constraints. This takes into account the hourly demand over time in a set of key regions, and hourly supply potential per technology. For each mix of variable renewables, the optimal curtailment and storage needs are estimated using the parametrizations from Ueckerdt et al. 68 . Compared to earlier treatment in FTT, this implies much improved and less conservative assumptions over limits to renewables in power grids due to intermittency 41 .
The baseline scenario (the only scenario in this paper) includes the EU Emission Trading System explicitly, as well as the ongoing nuclear phase-out in Germany and Belgium. Other policies are included implicitly by adding “gamma values” to the LCOE values used for decision-making by investors. These gamma values are calibrated to produce short-term projection of power capacity shares in each country that is consistent with the recent historical trend, by minimising the difference in rate of growth or decline at the changeover point between history and simulation. As a conservative assumption, we do not include a premature retirement of power plants when their marginal costs rise above the LCOE of newly installed power plants. We also do not include the possibility to extend the lifetimes of power plants.
The CAPEX and OPEX costs are derived from the IEA’s Projected Costs of Generating Electricity 2020 , and medians are used to fill in missing data. For solar, we use utility-scale solar prices. Residential solar power is more expensive, but the attractiveness for consumers is heightened by the fact they avoid various taxes on electricity. Standard deviations of these costs are also derived from this dataset; this means that volatility over time is not captured in our uncertainty.
This paper includes a further set of updates to FTT:Power that collectively favour the diffusion of solar PV into the electricity mix. Based on historical data from BNEF (see Supplementary Figure 4 ), we introduce learning in operational costs, rather than only in CAPEX, which mostly benefits offshore wind and solar PV. Learning rates are updated for key technologies, following Way et al. 8 . Both solar power and wind energy see a higher learning rate than previous model versions. Based on recent estimates of panel lifetime, we assume that a solar panel lasts 30 years on average.
Using BNEF data up to 2020, through a whole-model data upgrade, we update realised capacity factors for onshore, offshore, and solar technologies to the most recent values. The timescale for developing offshore wind projects is found to be longer than onshore wind, which hinders rapid growth.
The technical potential for onshore wind is updated using 69 , which has an improved resolution, threshold wind speed and turbine technical specifications compared to 70 . For solar power (solar PV and CSP), we updated the technical potential as the sum of 71 (utility-scale solar) and 72 (rooftop solar). We did not include a technical potential 57 for application of solar power on water (“floatovoltaics”), as this technology is still in early stages of development.
Regions with offshore potential, but no installed capacity, are attributed a small offshore wind capacity, equal to 1/100 the capacity of onshore wind installed in the region or country. Similar seeding is performed for CSP, which equals 1/100 the capacity of solar in the country. For countries without any onshore capacity, a small capacity, equal to 0.1% of historical generation, is added. This is because technology with zero deployment will never be selected. Historical installed capacity of renewables is inserted using 9 .
We innovate by introducing learning in storage technologies, which were, in the original model, fixed at the estimated 2030 price levels. For short-term storage we take the average of the learning rate for lithium-ion batteries and vanadium flow batteries. The latter are less common currently, but provide more flexibility and have a lower environmental impact 73 . The averaged learning exponent is 0.255 and long-term storage (assumed to be supplied by hydrogen) a more modest learning of 0.194 based on 8 . System storage costs are divided over the variable renewables. Both short-term storage costs and long-term storage costs increase with a poorer ratio between sun and wind. CSP only contributes to long-term storage costs, as it contains short-term storage internally. This is a conservative assumption for variable renewable energy diffusion, as policy may attribute storage costs to all grid participants or directly to customers.
The uncertainty analysis of Fig. 3 , Fig. 5 and Supplementary Figure 5 is performed with a Monte Carlo sampling of a set of input parameters. Input parameters were selected that had the largest expected impact on the diffusion of power generation technologies. In half of cases, costs of power storage were attributed equally among participants in the power market, whereas the costs of storage were allocated to renewables in the other half (the default). Inequality around access to capital between countries was modelled via the discount rate: the costs of finance (WACC/discount rate) was varied between 0.075 and 0.100 for countries in the OECD, and varied between 0.100 and 0.125 for all other countries. The learning rates for solar and wind were varied per the distribution given in Way et al. 8 . The importance of nonpecuniary aspects (gamma values), captured using calibration, was multiplied by a value drawn from the normal distribution N(1, 0.2). Similarly, fuel costs for gas and coal were varied by a factor drawn from the same normal distribution. Possible delays in grid expansion (f.i. to resolve grid congestion) are expressed as increasing the lead time of solar PV development with a Poisson distribution. The lifetime of solar panels was varied uniformly between 25 and 35 years.
The E3ME model is the macro-econometric component of the modelling framework. It is demand-led and features 70 regions and countries, covering the world. Each EU member and the UK has a representation of 70 sectors; other regions are represented to 43 economic sectors. The sectors are linked with input-output tables, and bilateral trade equations link the various regions and countries. The energy system within the E3ME model consists of equations for 23 fuel users (for instance chemical industry or air transport), and 12 fuel types (for instance electricity, or crude oil). Fifteen econometric regressions calibrated on data from 1970 to 2019 form the basis of the model. The model can be extended up to 2070. As a demand-led model, it first computes demand for final goods and services, and the supply of intermediate goods is estimated using input-output tables and bilateral trade relationships, which then drive employment, investment, income, induced productivity change, price levels and other macro variables 63 .
The IO tables are dynamically coupled to the FTT models via the energy balances. In specific, the coefficients for coal, oil and gas, manufactured fuels, electricity and “gas, steam & air conditioning” are adjusted based on the outcome of the FTT models.
The model uses World Bank estimates of historical GDP growth, the UN World Population Prospects for demographic change, and the IEA Energy Balances for energy demand growth, and the World Energy Outlook for baseline future energy demand 74 . The model does not incorporate the SSP framework, but our baseline can be compared most closely to SSP2 (the “middle of the road scenario” 38 . Philosophically, the model and SSP2 have the same narrative: a continuation of current trends.
Population growth in our model is slightly higher than SSP2, but economic growth is lower compared to SSP2 in many major economies (but always above SSP3). Total primary energy demand in 2050 is very similar to SSP2. For more details, see 61 .
Data availability
Historical generation and capacity of renewable energy from IRENA is available at https://irena.org/publications/2022/Apr/Renewable-Capacity-Statistics-2022 . Original data from BNEF and IEA are licensed by these owners, but datasets derived by the authors are available as part of the model code (see code availability). Source data for the figures are provided with this paper at https://doi.org/10.6084/m9.figshare.22659052 .
Code availability
The code for the standalone FTT model can be found at https://github.com/cpmodel/FTT_StandAlone/tree/Is_a_solar_future_inevitable 75 . This version was used for the uncertainty quantification of Figs. 3 and 5 . The computer code for the full E3ME-FTT model needed to replicate the study is licensed and not available publicly, but can be obtained from the authors upon reasonable request.
IPCC. Global Warming of 1.5 °C: An IPCC Special Report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5 °C above pre-industrial levels and related global greenhouse gas emission pathways, in the context of strengthening the global response to the threat of climate change, sustainable development, and efforts to eradicate poverty . (Cambridge University Press, 2018). https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009157940 .
Dooley, K. & Kartha, S. Land-based negative emissions: Risks for climate mitigation and impacts on sustainable development. Int Environ. Agreem. 18 , 79–98 (2018).
Google Scholar
Tanzer, S. E. & Ramírez, A. When are negative emissions negative emissions? Energy Environ. Sci. 12 , 1210–1218 (2019).
Sachverständigenrat. Energiewende: Umsteuern zu einer globalen Klimapolitik. in Zeit für Reformen (Bonifatius GmbH Druck-Buch-Verlag, 2016).
Grubb, M. et al. Induced innovation in energy technologies and systems: a review of evidence and potential implications for CO2 mitigation. Environ. Res. Lett. 16 , 043007 (2021).
ADS CAS Google Scholar
Lindman, Å. & Söderholm, P. Wind energy and green economy in Europe: Measuring policy-induced innovation using patent data. Appl. Energy 179 , 1351–1359 (2016).
Grubb, M. et al. The New Economics of Innovation and Transition: Evaluating Opportunities and Risks . https://eeist.co.uk/download/557/ (2021).
Way, R., Mealy, P., Farmer, J. D. & Ives, M. Empirically grounded technology forecasts and the energy transition. INET Oxford Working Paper No. 2021-01 (2021).
IRENA. Renewable Capacity Statistics 2021 . International Renewable Energy Agency (2021).
Ziegler, M. S. & Trancik, J. E. Re-examining rates of lithium-ion battery technology improvement and cost decline. Energy Environ. Sci. 14 , 1635–1651 (2021).
Tong, D. et al. Geophysical constraints on the reliability of solar and wind power worldwide. Nat. Commun. 12 , 1–12 (2021).
Sivaram, V. & Kann, S. Solar power needs a more ambitious cost target. Nat. Energy. 1 , 1–3 (2016).
Ameli, N. et al. Higher cost of finance exacerbates a climate investment trap in developing economies. Nat. Commun. 12 , 1–12 (2021).
IEA (International Energy Agency). The Role of Critical Minerals in Clean Energy Transitions . (2021).
Markard, J.;, Geels, F. W.; & Raven, R. Challenges in the acceleration of sustainability transitions. Environ. Res. Lett. 15 , (2020).
Way, R., Mealy, P., Farmer, J. D. & Ives, M. Empirically grounded technology forecasts and the energy transition. Joule 1–26 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joule.2022.08.009 (2022).
Meng, J., Way, R., Verdolini, E. & Anadon, L. D. Comparing expert elicitation and model-based probabilistic technology cost forecasts for the energy transition. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. 118 , e1917165118 (2021).
CAS PubMed PubMed Central Google Scholar
International Energy Agency. World Energy Outlook 2021 . www.iea.org/weo (2021).
Wilson, C., Grubler, A., Bauer, N., Krey, V. & Riahi, K. Future capacity growth of energy technologies: Are scenarios consistent with historical evidence? Clim. Change 118 , 381–395 (2013).
ADS Google Scholar
Grubler, A. et al. A low energy demand scenario for meeting the 1.5 °C target and sustainable development goals without negative emission technologies. Nat. Energy 3 , 515–527 (2018).
Victoria, M. et al. Solar photovoltaics is ready to power a sustainable future . Joule vol. 5 1041–1056 (Cell Press, 2021).
Nemet, G. How solar energy became cheap: a model for low-carbon innovation . (Taylor & Francis, 2019).
Rogers, E. Diffusion of Innovations . (Free Press, 2003).
Farmer, J. D. & Lafond, F. How predictable is technological progress? Res Policy 45 , 647–665 (2016).
Sharpe, S. & Lenton, T. M. Upward-scaling tipping cascades to meet climate goals: plausible grounds for hope. 21 , 421–433 https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2020.1870097 (2021).
Sweerts, B., Detz, R. J. & van der Zwaan, B. Evaluating the Role of Unit Size in Learning-by-Doing of Energy Technologies. Joule 4 , 967–970 (2020).
Wilson, C. et al. Granular technologies to accelerate decarbonization: Smaller, modular energy technologies have advantages. Science (1979) 368 , 36–39 (2020).
CAS Google Scholar
Malhotra, A. & Schmidt, T. S. Accelerating Low-Carbon Innovation. Joule 4 , 2259–2267 (2020).
Roy, P., Kumar Sinha, N., Tiwari, S. & Khare, A. A review on perovskite solar cells: Evolution of architecture, fabrication techniques, commercialization issues and status. Solar Energy 198 , 665–688 (2020).
Ma, S. et al. Development of encapsulation strategies towards the commercialization of perovskite solar cells. Energy. Environ. Sci. https://doi.org/10.1039/d1ee02882k (2022).
Egli, F., Steffen, B. & Schmidt, T. S. A dynamic analysis of financing conditions for renewable energy technologies. Nat. Energy. 3 , 1084–1092 (2018).
Daniela-Abigail, H. L. et al. Does recycling solar panels make this renewable resource sustainable? Evidence supported by environmental, economic, and social dimensions. Sustain Cities Soc. 77 , 103539 (2022).
Ziegler, M. S., Song, J. & Trancik, J. E. Determinants of lithium-ion battery technology cost decline. Energy Environ. Sci. 14 , 6074–6098 (2021).
Jaxa-Rozen, M. & Trutnevyte, E. Sources of uncertainty in long-term global scenarios of solar photovoltaic technology. Nat. Clim. Change. 11 , 266–273 (2021).
Li, F. G. N., Trutnevyte, E. & Strachan, N. A review of socio-technical energy transition (STET) models. Technol. Forecast Soc. Change 100 , 290–305 (2015).
Wilson, C. Up-scaling, formative phases, and learning in the historical diffusion of energy technologies. Energy Policy 50 , 81–94 (2012).
BloombergNEF. 2H 2020 LCOE Data Viewer (2021).
Riahi, K. et al. The Shared Socioeconomic Pathways and their energy, land use, and greenhouse gas emissions implications: An overview. Glob. Environ. Change 42 , 153–168 (2017).
IRENA. Future of Solar Photovoltaic: Deployment, investment, technology, grid integration and socio-economic aspects (A Global Energy Transformation paper ). (International Renewable Energy Agency, 2019).
Matsuo, Y. et al. Investigating the economics of the power sector under high penetration of variable renewable energies. Appl Energy 267 , 113956 (2020).
Simsek, Y. et al. FTT: Power 2.0: A global simulation model of power technology diffusion with learning-by-doing and renewables integration. In preperation .
Climate Policy Initiative. Global Landscape of Climate Finance 2021 . (2021).
Kling, G., Volz, U., Murinde, V. & Ayas, S. The impact of climate vulnerability on firms’ cost of capital and access to finance. World Dev. 137 , 105131 (2021).
Rickman, J., Kothari, S., Larosa, F. & Ameli, N. The Unequal Distribution of International Climate Finance Flows and Its Underlying Drivers. https://doi.org/10.21203/RS.3.RS-1188981/V1 (2022).
Ameli, N., Kothari, S. & Grubb, M. Misplaced expectations from climate disclosure initiatives. Nat. Clim. Change. 11 , 917–924 (2021).
Bilir, L. K., Chor, D. & Manova, K. Host-country financial development and multinational activity. Eur. Econ. Rev. 115 , 192–220 (2019).
Kreibiehl, S., et al. Investment and finance. in Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (ed. Shukla P. R., et al) (Cambridge University Press, 2022). https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009157926.017 .
Kleijn, R., van der Voet, E., Kramer, G. J., van Oers, L. & van der Giesen, C. Metal requirements of low-carbon power generation. Energy 36 , 5640–5648 (2011).
Vidal, O., Goffé, B. & Arndt, N. Metals for a low-carbon society. Nat. Geosci. 6 , 894–896 (2013).
Sonter, L. J., Dade, M. C., Watson, J. E. M. & Valenta, R. K. Renewable energy production will exacerbate mining threats to biodiversity. Nat. Commun. 11 , 1–6 (2020).
Gielen, D. Critical minerals for the energy transition . (International Renewable Energy Agency, 2021).
Coulomb, R., Dietz, S., Maria Godunova, T. B. N. Critical Minerals Today and in 2030: An Analysis for OECD Countries . https://doi.org/10.1787/19970900 (2015).
Ali, S. H. et al. Mineral supply for sustainable development requires resource governance. Nat. 2017 543:7645 543 , 367–372 (2017).
Masson-Delmotte, V. et al. Global warming of 1.5 °C. An IPCC Special Report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5 °C above pre-industrial levels and related global greenhouse gas emission pathways, in the context of strengthening the global response to the threat of climate change . (Cambridge University Press, 2018).
Miskin, C. K. et al. Sustainable co-production of food and solar power to relax land-use constraints. Nat. Sustainab. 2019 2:10 2 , 972–980 (2019).
Deshmukh, R., Wu, G. C., Callaway, D. S. & Phadke, A. Geospatial and techno-economic analysis of wind and solar resources in India. Renew. Energy 134 , 947–960 (2019).
Almeida, R. M. et al. Floating solar power could help fight climate change — let’s get it right. Nat. 606 , 246–249 (2022).
Pai, S., Emmerling, J., Drouet, L., Zerriffi, H. & Jewell, J. Meeting well-below 2 °C target would increase energy sector jobs globally. One Earth 4 , 1026–1036 (2021).
Newell, P. & Mulvaney, D. The political economy of the ‘just transition’. Geogr. J. 179 , 132–140 (2013).
Semieniuk, G., Campiglio, E., Mercure, J. F., Volz, U. & Edwards, N. R. Low-carbon transition risks for finance. WIREs: Climate Change 12 , e678 (2021).
Mercure, J. F. et al. Environmental impact assessment for climate change policy with the simulation-based integrated assessment model E3ME-FTT-GENIE. Energy Strategy Rev. 20 , 195–208 (2018).
Trutnevyte, E. et al. Societal Transformations in Models for Energy and Climate Policy: The Ambitious Next Step. One Earth . 1 , 423–433 (2019).
Mercure, J. F. et al. Reframing incentives for climate policy action. Nat. Energy 6 , 1133–1143 (2021).
Mercure, J.-F. F., Lam, A., Billington, S. & Pollitt, H. Integrated assessment modelling as a positive science: private passenger road transport policies to meet a climate target well below 2 °C. Clim. Change 151 , 109–129 (2018).
ADS PubMed PubMed Central Google Scholar
Knobloch, F., Pollitt, H., Chewpreecha, U., Daioglou, V. & Mercure, J. F. Simulating the deep decarbonisation of residential heatingfor limiting global warming to 1.5 °C. Energy Effic. 12 , 521–550 (2019).
Vercoulen, P. et al. Carbon-Neutral Steel Production and Its Impact on the Economies of China, Japan, and Korea: A Simulation with E3ME-FTT:Steel. Energies 2023 16 , 4498 (2023). Vol. 16, Page 4498 .
Mercure, J.-F. An age structured demographic theory of technological change. J Evol Econ 25 , (2015).
Ueckerdt, F. et al. Decarbonizing global power supply under region-specific consideration of challenges and options of integrating variable renewables in the REMIND model. Energy Econ. 64 , 665–684 (2017).
Bosch, J., Staffell, I. & Hawkes, A. D. Temporally-explicit and spatially-resolved global onshore wind energy potentials. Energy 131 , 207–217 (2017).
Hoogwijk, M. On the global and regional potential of renewable energy sources. (Utrecht University, 2004).
Teske, S., Nagrath, K., Morris, T. & Dooley, K. Renewable energy resource assessment. Achieving the Paris Climate Agreement Goals: Global and Regional 100% Renewable Energy Scenarios with Non-Energy GHG Pathways for +1.5C and +2C 161–173 https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05843-2_7/TABLES/3 (Springer Cham, 2019).
Joshi, S. et al. High resolution global spatiotemporal assessment of rooftop solar photovoltaics potential for renewable electricity generation. Nat. Commun. 12 , 1–15 (2021).
da Silva Lima, L. et al. Life cycle assessment of lithium-ion batteries and vanadium redox flow batteries-based renewable energy storage systems. Sustain. Energy Technol. Assess. 46 , 101286 (2021).
Bui, H. et al. E3ME Model Manual v9.0 . www.e3me.com (2022).
FTT Community. FTT:Power Standalone. Available at https://zenodo.org/badge/latestdoi/579188103 (2023).
Download references
Acknowledgements
JFM, FJMMN and PV received funding from the UK Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy (BEIS) from the EEIST project. NA acknowledges support from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (grant agreement No 802891), a grant which also funded SK., FL and JR. We would like to thank Simon Sharpe for discussion that improved the discussion on policy implications. We would also like to thank Doyne Farmer for his valuable feedback.
Author information
Authors and affiliations.
Global Systems Institute, Department of Geography, University of Exeter, Exeter, UK
Femke J. M. M. Nijsse, Jean-Francois Mercure & Pim Vercoulen
Cambridge Centre for Energy, Environment and Natural Resource Governance, University of Cambridge, Cambridge, UK
Jean-Francois Mercure & Hector Pollitt
The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA
Institute for Sustainable Resources, University College London, London, UK
Nadia Ameli, Francesca Larosa, Sumit Kothari & Jamie Rickman
Royal Institute of Technology (KTH), Climate Action Centre, Stockholm, Sweden
Francesca Larosa
Cambridge Econometrics, Cambridge, UK
Pim Vercoulen
You can also search for this author in PubMed Google Scholar
Contributions
F.J.M.M.N. coordinated and performed the research, with contributions from J.-F.M., and N.A. F.J.M.M.N and J.-F.M. wrote the article with support from N.A., S.K. and F.L. N.A., F.L, S.K., and J.R. collected the BNEF data. F.J.M.M.N. led the model improvements and ran the simulations, with support from P.V., J.-F.M and H.P.
Corresponding author
Correspondence to Femke J. M. M. Nijsse .
Ethics declarations
Competing interests.
The authors declare no competing interests.
Peer review
Peer review information.
Nature Communications thanks the anonymous reviewers for their contribution to the peer review of this work. A peer review file is available.
Additional information
Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Supplementary information
Supplementary information, peer review file, rights and permissions.
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .
Reprints and permissions
About this article
Cite this article.
Nijsse, F.J.M.M., Mercure, JF., Ameli, N. et al. The momentum of the solar energy transition. Nat Commun 14 , 6542 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-023-41971-7
Download citation
Received : 25 August 2022
Accepted : 25 September 2023
Published : 17 October 2023
DOI : https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-023-41971-7
Share this article
Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:
Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.
Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative
This article is cited by
Machine learning and deep learning models based grid search cross validation for short-term solar irradiance forecasting.
- Doaa El-Shahat
- Ahmed Tolba
- Mohamed Abdel-Basset
Journal of Big Data (2024)
From niches to norms: the promise of social tipping interventions to scale climate action
- Veronica Pizziol
- Alessandro Tavoni
npj Climate Action (2024)
Advanced photovoltaic technology can reduce land requirements and climate impact on energy generation
- Ankita Saxena
- Calum Brown
- Mark Rounsevell
Communications Earth & Environment (2024)
Impacts of large-scale deployment of vertical bifacial photovoltaics on European electricity market dynamics
- Laszlo Szabo
- Magda Moner- Girona
- Sandor Szabo
Nature Communications (2024)
Quick links
- Explore articles by subject
- Guide to authors
- Editorial policies
Sign up for the Nature Briefing newsletter — what matters in science, free to your inbox daily.
IMAGES
COMMENTS
Jun 11, 2022 · Solar energy is environmentally friendly technology, a great energy supply and one of the most significant renewable and green energy sources. It plays a substantial role in achieving sustainable development energy solutions. Therefore, the massive amount of solar energy attainable daily makes it a very attractive resource for generating ...
Nov 1, 2023 · This review paper attempts to highlight the gap between academic energy research and its ultimate observable impact on the energy industry of nations. For each country, a comprehensive effort is made to define the current operational solar power status and its corresponding academic solar energy research.
The term "solar energy" in this context includes the indirect uses such as wind energy and biomass. Because of the international character of Solar Energy, articles that deal solely with the solar radiation or wind data base of a specific country are not normally considered suitable for Solar Energy. Submitted manuscripts may take the form of ...
May 19, 2021 · Solar PV modules have maintained a learning rate of 23% since 1976, i.e., their cost reduces by 23% every time the capacity doubles. 39 The main drivers for solar cost reductions include technological improvements, such as efficiency increase 40, 41 and those described in Note S1, and high-level mechanisms, 41 including economies of scale ...
Dec 31, 2019 · PDF | Solar Energy is the prime important source of energy, and it has continued to gain popularity globally. As of 2018, about 486 GW of solar PV was... | Find, read and cite all the research you ...
Dec 2, 2024 · Read the latest Research articles in Solar energy from Scientific Reports. ... Solar energy articles within Scientific Reports. Featured. Article 03 December 2024 | Open Access.
Dec 16, 2024 · Highly renewable energy systems, built on wind, solar PV, and sectoral integration, ... Research Open Access 16 Dec 2024 Nature Communications. Volume: 15, P: 10680.
Oct 17, 2023 · Solar energy is the most widely available energy resource on Earth, and its economic attractiveness is improving fast in a cycle of increasing investments. ... Research articles Reviews & Analysis ...
Dec 31, 2020 · The study concludes by emphasizing the need for ongoing research, technological innovation, and strategic planning to fully unlock solar energy's potential in the transition towards a sustainable ...
Jan 1, 2020 · Solar energy is categories as a renewable source of energy which has been developing to an extent scale due to ... This research article presents low-cost wireless sensor monitoring systems for ...